Intellectual Property Rights and Public Health:

How Pharmaceutical Patents Save Lives

 

J.S. Liechty

November 28, 2006

Biology Senior Seminar

 

 

 

 

Thesis

 

The government’s unwavering support of intellectual property rights and patent laws in the pharmaceutical industry plays a vital role in the development of new lifesaving drugs.

 

 

Outline

 

I. Intro, Rationale & Background Information

II. Role of Patents in Innovation

          A. The Nature of Research and Development

          B. Economic Incentive for Innovation

III. Threats to Intellectual Property in the Pharmaceutical Industry

          A. The Cipro Case

          B. NIH and Public Funding

                   1.  Background on NIH

                   2.  Bayh-Dole Act

          C. The Norvir Case

IV.  Conclusion: Looking Toward the Future

V.  Bibliography

 

 

 

Introduction & Rationale

The continued development of new medicines and pharmaceuticals plays an essential role in the progress of the modern day health system.  Not only can the development of new drugs enable new forms of treatment, but new drugs can also lower overall costs of traditional treatments (Barrett & Carey, 2001).  With the essential role pharmaceuticals play in our healthcare system, it is evident just how important continued research and development in this field is.  At the current time, the incentive for private organizations to develop new drugs is twofold.  These incentives include: an increased quality of life for fellow human beings and a large money making opportunity.  The latter has been the incentive for the most important breakthroughs of our age and will continue to be so for the foreseeable future.  The role of intellectual property rights and government upheld patents on discovered drugs are crucial to the continued investment in research and development by private means.  By upholding patent laws in the pharmaceutical industry, the government has ensured the intellectual property rights of newly discovered drugs.  This has enabled pharmaceutical companies to invest millions in the costly research and development without fear of losing their return on the money invested.  The government’s unwavering support of intellectual property rights and patent laws in the pharmaceutical industry plays a vital role in the development of new lifesaving drugs.  This paper will highlight the role patents play in the development of new drugs and will argue the case for the continued support of patent laws in the pharmaceutical industry worldwide.

Background on Intellectual Property

In order to fully understand the issues at hand, let us start by looking into what intellectual property is and what purpose intellectual property rights and patents serve.  The World Intellectual Property Organization characterizes intellectual property as “creations of the human mind” (World Intellectual Property Organization, n.d.).  This includes literary, artistic, and scientific works.  Scientific discoveries are specifically mentioned as intellectual property by the World Intellectual Property Organization.  Intellectual property falls into two categories: copyrights and industrial property.  The latter is the one that pertains to pharmaceutical products.  Industrial property includes patents on inventions, scientific discoveries and things of that nature.  Patents are considered to be “the right granted to an inventor by a State… which allows the inventor to exclude anyone else from commercially exploiting his invention for a limited period.” The rationale behind patents is that they “provide incentives to individuals, offering them recognition for their creativity and material reward for their marketable inventions. These incentives encourage innovation, which in turn contributes to the continuing enhancement of the quality of human life” (World Intellectual Property Organization, n.d.).  Patents act to protect intellectual property and thereby benefit both the inventor and the general public.  By ensuring intellectual property rights, a state can promote innovation and development of new products that are beneficial to everyone.  Applying this notion to the pharmaceutical industry, the State encourages the development of useful new chemicals by giving monetary reward to those who contribute to the development of new pharmaceuticals. 

The Role of Patents in Innovation

The Nature of Private Research and Development

          In the United States, all producers of pharmaceuticals are private companies.  As such, these businesses need to make money in order to stay afloat in the marketplace.  The route that most companies choose to do this is by offering unique products to their consumers.  In order to accomplish this, pharmaceutical companies must somehow acquire the rights to be the sole producer of a drug.  Whether the company chooses to do their own research and development or buy licenses to produce chemicals discovered by others, patents play an important part of the company’s ability to recover sunk costs.  Research and development of marketable pharmaceuticals is a costly endeavor to undertake, and will not be done by private means without the chance of turning the investment into a large moneymaker.  The cost of developing a drug to the marketable stage is estimated to be between $800 million and $2 billion per drug (Barrett and Carey, 2001 and Masia, 2006).  The hefty price tag for developing a drug goes to a number of places including laboratory work to investigate and identify a wide variety of potentially useful chemicals, testing to eliminate candidates, and clinical trials to pass regulations before being approved for the market.  This whole process usually takes 12 to 15 years.  On top of recovering costs associated with research that results in marketable drugs, pharmaceutical companies must also recoup costs from failed research ventures (Masia, 2006). 

          With the ever-climbing costs of research and development and the far off return on investment, investor confidence plays a huge role in the continued development of new pharmaceuticals.  Unwavering governmental assurance of property rights is one important way that investor confidence is bolstered (Wayne, 2006).  If investors are unsure that intellectual property will be protected, they will be hesitant to invest the money needed to develop new drugs.  In this way, any attack on property rights is also an attack on the future of private drug development.  If private funding is going to continue to be the driving force behind the discovery of new drugs, companies and investors alike will have to continue to be able to make money at what they are doing.  If pharmaceutical companies are to continue taking risks with large sums of money, they are going to need to continue receiving large sums of money in return.  To investors, the bigger the risk, the bigger the reward will need to be.  Governmental interference in the pharmaceutical industry will translate directly into interference in investment and thus development.  If the government does not continue to respect intellectual property rights in all cases, companies will no longer be willing to invest the large sums of money necessary to develop new lifesaving (and money saving) drugs.  In the early 1990s there was significant pressure on Congress to pass a price ceiling on newly developed drugs.  Professor of Pharmacy Eugene M. Kolassa says that if the government had placed price ceilings on drugs, “there would be no new protease inhibitors now.”  Those new drugs have cut down on hospital costs as well as deaths for HIV patients (Barrett & Carey, 2001).  Judith Kaufmann (2006) seconds this claim, saying, “Drugs that cure AIDS and many other diseases are available precisely because of patent protection.”  Research into new drugs will be greatly handicapped if price ceilings are implemented or pharmaceutical patents are no longer honored.  

Economic Incentive for Innovation

By using an economic incentive for discovery and development, the government will most effectively promote the production of medicines that will be useful for many years to come.  As the Assistant Secretary of State for Economic and Business Affairs puts it, “the inventor is granted an economic incentive to take risks and create; the public receives the benefit of the invention, as well as the inventor's knowledge for application in other uses” (Wayne, 2006).  With average patent life spans of only 20 years, it is well worth the pharmaceutical company making an exorbitant profit (Kaufmann, 2006 & World Intellectual Property Organization, n.d.).  Even if the price set by pharmaceutical companies is too high for most people to afford, the company is providing a drug that wouldn’t otherwise be available.  In 20 short years that product will be opened up to competition and market forces, which will inevitably bring down the price. 

 

Threats to Intellectual Property in the Pharmaceutical Industry

The Cipro Case

Over the past few decades there have been a number of instances in which pharmaceutical patents have come under threat.  One memorable case in which this has happened is the case of Cipro in 2001.  During the anthrax outbreak in September and October of 2001, the US government became concerned over the availability and price of Cipro, an antibiotic that has proven especially effective against anthrax.  Bayer A.G., the maker of the antibiotic Cipro, was charging over $4 per tablet at the time.  Citing concerns of national security, Secretary of Health and Human Services, Tommy G. Thompson, threatened to circumvent Bayer’s patent on Cipro.  Barr Laboratories stated that it could produce a generic version of Cipro for under $1 if the Bayer patent would be laid aside.  Thompson demanded that Bayer match this price or the government would overrule their patent 3 years before it expired (Andrews & Bradsher, 2001).  Feeling a great deal of pressure, Bayer made a special deal with the government.  In order to keep their patent, they agreed to sell millions of tablets of Cipro to the government for 95 cents a piece.  Bayer also donated 2 million tablets of Cipro to the government free of charge (Bradsher, 2001).  This kind of governmental bullying is the very thing that needs to be avoided if investors are going to continue to support research into the development of new pharmaceuticals.  The government’s role is to uphold patents, not to usurp them. 

National Institutes of Health and Public Funding

The issue becomes more complex when public funding goes towards laboratory research that later results in a patent and marketable product.  When taxpayer money has helped to fund the discovery of a marketable product, what rights does the government have to interfere in price or availability of the product?  Does the patent really belong to the taxpayers themselves?  These are questions that the National Institutes for Health (NIH) deals with.  There are many cases in which the NIH gives money to scientific research which later turns into a product on the market.  The NIH has, for the most part, refrained from interfering with the marketing of products that it has helped to develop.  Before we delve into any of these cases, let us first turn our attention to the role of the NIH.

The NIH is a part of the US Department of Health and Human Services.  According to their official website, the NIH is the “primary Federal agency for conducting and supporting medical research” (National Institutes of Health, 2006).  The NIH does its own internal research into drug development as well as financially supporting research at universities, hospitals, and research institutes.  When the NIH supports research that results in a marketable product, the institution that has conducted the research owns the intellectual property rights under the Bayh-Dole Act.  

In order to promote the commercialization of technologies that have sprung from publicly funded research, the US Congress passed the Bayh-Dole Act in 1980.  This act gives universities and other research institutes intellectual property rights to any invention that comes out of publicly funded research.  This act relates specifically to the pharmaceutical industry as NIH funded research leads to the marketability of a drug.  Under this act, the government reserved what are termed as “march in rights” on the products.  March in rights allow the government to step in when it feels that an institution is not using their invention to further human well-being. The NIH is limited as to where it may interfere with the private sector concerning patents under the Bayh-Dole Act.  As long as the product is widely available to those seeking it, the NIH can’t interfere with the marketing of any product that falls under Bayh-Dole.  The NIH states that they have no authority to control pricing of drugs, and that drug pricing is an issue to be addressed by Congress (Connolly, 2006).  As it stands, the government’s only legal interference with publicly funded drugs is to ensure that they are made widely available.  In short, the private sector may profit from public investment.  The NIH trusts that the taxpayers will get a return on their money with the availability of a new useful product on the market (National Institutes of Health, 2001).

The Norvir Case

One instance in which these issues have been played out was the case of Norvir in 2004.  Norvir is an antiretroviral drug produced by Abbott Laboratories that has proven especially effective in combating AIDS.  Late in 2003, Abbott Laboratories raised the price of a daily dose from $1.75 to $8.57 (Connolly, 2006).  This is of special note because the NIH gave a $3.5 million grant towards the research that resulted in Norvir.  AIDS activists filed a petition for the NIH to invoke their march in rights to counter what was described as unfair pricing on an essential product.  The movement to interfere with Abbott Laboratory’s marketing and pricing was based on the grounds that Norvir was supported with public funds and is now making private profits.  The NIH decided that Abbott’s price hike was outside the realm of their jurisdiction.  In addition to the NIH petition, the Bush administration was also asked to nullify the patents held for Norvir so that generics could be produced and put on the market at a lower price (Connolly, 2006).  While the government has made provisions under the Bayh-Dole Act to commercialize products such as Norvir, there is still a significant threat to the patent holders in such cases.  The purpose of the Bayh-Dole Act is to promote research to be developed into something that is useful to society.  The NIH argues that with the Bayh-Dole Act in place, products such as Norvir would never have been developed and wouldn’t be available to anyone (National Institutes of Health, 2001).

The use of public funds to support research that results in private profit does raise some serious questions.  Should the NIH be the patent holder of any discovery that comes out of NIH funded research?  What rights should the taxpayer have to the product it helped to finance in development?  Should the NIH receive royalties from successful patents?  While these questions remain to be fully answered, one thing that is certain is the need for the unwavering backing of patents.  The threat of governmental circumvention of pharmaceutical patents as seen in the cases of Cipro and Norvir is something that must not be taken lightly.  The federal government must abstain from interfering in such cases in order to preserve the future of drug discovery. 

 

Looking Toward the Future

While the future of the pharmaceutical industry remains to be seen, a few conclusions can be drawn from its past.  Prices of developing new drugs as well as costs to the consumer are clearly on the rise (Barrett & Casey, 2001).  While new scientific techniques have greatly expanded the tools available to drug developers, research costs have increased correspondingly.  While the pharmaceutical industry deals with the issue of rising development costs, the question has been posed “How can we encourage research and still keep prices within reach?” (Barrett & Casey, 2001).  This is a question that is not easily answered, and even less easily accomplished.  While the world struggles to solve this problem, one fact remains sure: the current pharmaceutical industry (and health care system) relies very heavily on intellectual property rights and patents.  As long as the private sector is responsible for developing new drugs, patents must be upheld at all costs. 

The role of the government in assisting private institutions in developing new lifesaving drugs is one that cannot be overstressed.  Simply put, governmentally upheld patents in the pharmaceutical industry have saved countless lives (and dollars), and will continue to do so for as long as they are in place.  Any threat to pharmaceutical patents is a threat to the future of our health care system.  We cannot afford to overstep the intellectual property rights in the pharmaceutical industry for any reason, including special circumstances of national security.  If the government appropriates patents that are particularly needed or extensively used, they are also taking away the incentive for companies to develop other important drugs.  By ensuring intellectual property rights in the pharmaceutical industry, privately funded research will continue to develop new lifesaving drugs that will be greatly beneficial to society.

 

 

Bibliography

 

Andrews, E., & Bradsher, K.  (2001, October 24).  A Nation Challenged: Cipro: U.S. Says Bayer Will Cut Cost of its Anthrax Drug.  The New York Times.  Retrieved November 28, 2006 from the New York Times website: http://query.nytimes.com/gst/fullpage.html?sec=health&res=9D03E1D71431F937A15753C1A9679C8B63&n=Top%2fReference%2fTimes%20Topics%2fPeople%2fT%2fThompson%2c%20Tommy%20G%2e

 

Barrett, A., & Carey, J.  (2001).  Drug Prices: What’s Fair?  Retrieved November 28, 2006 from the Business Week website: http://www.businessweek.com/magazine/content/01_50/b3761001.htm

 

Bradsher, K.  (2001, October 25).  A Nation Challenged: The Cost; Bayer Agrees to Charge Government a Lower Price for Anthrax Medicine.  The New York Times.  Retrieved November 28, 2006 from the New York Times website: http://query.nytimes.com/gst/fullpage.html?res=9F07E7D91231F936A15753C1A9679C8B63&sec=health&pagewanted=1

 

Connolly, C.  (2004).  NIH Declines to Enter AIDS Drug Price Battle.  Retrieved November 28, 2006 from the Washington Post website: http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/articles/A40430-2004Aug4.html

 

Gay Stolberg, S. and Gerth, J.  (2000).  Drug Firms Reap Profits on Tax-Backed Research.  Retrieved November 28, 2006 from the New York Times website:  http://www.nytimes.com/library/national/science/042300hth-drugs.html

 

Grubb, P. (1999). Patents for Chemicals, Pharmaceuticals, and Biotechnology Fundamentals of Global Law, Practice, and Strategy. New York: Oxford University Press.

 

Kaufmann, J. (2006).  Intellectual Property Rights and the Pharmaceutical Industry.  Retrieved November 28, 2006 from the US State Department website: http://usinfo.state.gov/products/pubs/intelprp/industry.htm

 

Masia, N.  (2006).  The Cost of Developing a New Drug.  Retrieved November 28, 2006 from the US State Department website: http://usinfo.state.gov/products/pubs/intelprp/cost.htm

 

National Institutes of Health.  (2001).  A Plan to Ensure Taxpayers’ Interests are Protected.  Retrieved November 28, 2006 from the National Institutes of Health website: http://www.nih.gov/news/070101wyden.htm

 

National Institutes of Health.  (2006).  Overview of NIH.  Retrieved November 28, 2006 from the National Institutes of Health website: http://www.nih.gov/about/NIHoverview.html

 

Rosack, J.  (2002).  NIH Shows Taxpayers What Their Dollars Are Buying.  Psychiatric News, Volume 37 Number 7.  Retrieved November 28, 2006 from the Psychiatric News website: http://pn.psychiatryonline.org/cgi/content/full/37/7/8

 

Wayne, E. A.  (2006).  Why Protecting Intellectual Property Rights Matters.  Retrieved November 28, 2006 from the US State Department website: http://usinfo.state.gov/products/pubs/intelprp/protecting.htm

 

World Intellectual Property Organization.  (n.d.).  Understanding Intellectual Property.  Publication No. 895.  Retrieved November 28, 2006 from the WIPO website: http://www.wipo.int/freepublications/en/intproperty/895/wipo_pub_895.pdf